A commodity produced by machinery
to which labor-power has been put (little or no skill required now) has within
it both exchange valueand value as a utilitarian item. The
capitalist is interested in the commodity’s exchange value for in that
act (of exchange) he can realize (materialize) the surplus value
inherent in the system of production wherein the workers are paid at one rate (value)
and the actual realized value of what they produced is considerably greater.
This is true because within the commodity is also paid and unpaid
labor-power, as we are about to see.
The Category of “Form”
Determines a Commodity’s Destination
The form of the surplus value
produced determines where commodities must go. In other words, if I am a
capitalist producing iron I have to sell it to another capitalist (somewhere in
the world) who can use it to make something - for example, steel. In this sense
humanity is still in a rather primitive condition where the raw characteristics
of the articles created, dictates what must happen thereafter. A useful way to
picture this is to think of the “opposite” of destination being determined by
form, as one sees when we think of a STAR TREK replicating machine. You ask the
machine for a cup of coffee and the cup, filled with coffee, materializes. In
this futuristic vision the value and surplus value inherent in the system of
production are liquid (transmutable) and “form” means nothing. If we assume
that this future society is a Communist system, where there is no money, no
classes, no war, etc. such advanced
technological conditions make sense - a la Gene
Roddenberry’s presentation of the
future. Under such hypothetical conditions in the future, value and surplus
value are truly free and can be transmuted at will into whatever form.
That is not the situation now, nor
has it ever been, in the history of capitalism (or in the history of the
world.) We are still stuck with the fact that whatever the form of a commodity
produced may be, so its destination is pre-determined. People don’t eat iron -
only certain other industries can absorb it - and, thus the surplus value
within it.
The Category of “Labor-power”
Technically speaking the moment human
labor was commoditized as “labor-power” we had the emergence of the
germinal of capitalism. By “commoditized as labor-power” in capitalism we mean that
a group of workers in a factory put out so much labor per unit time -
that unit of time is measured by the factory clock. Some workers may be
more efficient than others but for purposes of the “commodity” of
labor-power it is whatever the average homogenized output per hour may
be. Let’s say it again: labor-power as a category and as a commodity is
the homogenized (averaged) factory-clock governed,
collective output of a group of factory workers.
Prehistorically, and in the Ancient
World, before factory clocks and without machines of the typology (diagnostics)
listed below labor-power may also have been proto-commoditized as I have
discussed above, in a few examples, but these represent only
“proto-commoditization.”
Mathematics
of Social Production
Note: In a truly abstract sense, in our
equations, we have stripped the entire matter of social production to its
essence (four elements). These are (a) labor-power (b) technology (in the case
of capitalism it is machinofacture; in our time automated and cybernetized
machinofacture) (c) value and (d) surplus value. You may think of labor-power
in our equations as having two sub-elements consisting of (i) the three
dimensions of work with machinery, collectively undertaken, to which we add
(ii) a fourth temporal dimension. Thus, work may (i) be measured and made
more-or-less efficient in the mechanical performance sense and (ii) the necessary time it takes said work socially to occur (e.g., the way workers are organized within the factory and at the
factory bench), may likewise be treated as a separate sub-element.
Socially Necessary Labor-Time
The collective labor-power input of a
group of factory workers constitutes socially necessary labor-time in
capitalist production. However, in pre-capitalist stages socially necessary
labor-time is far less of a precise quantitatively determinable category.
Nevertheless, it is critically important to cross-cultural analysis. This is
true because in the Primitive World, and in the
Ancient World (Slavery and early Feudalism) work also had a measured character.
Socially necessary labor-time input was understood, if not precisely
quantified, by those concerned. As such, socially necessary labor-time is a
broader and more flexible category than labor-power (with its rigorous method
of factory bench homogenizing, and factory clock measuring, of labor input.)
Furthermore, the very inherent nature of the capitalist system of factory
production makes paid and unpaid labor-power the basis for extracting profit as
we are about to see. It is this very nature of capitalism which makes it a
legalized system of theft.
The Law of Value
The scientific definition of
value in its general sense is the amount of socially necessary
labor-time involved in production of some given commodity. In Capitalism, value
is the amount of socially necessary labor time it takes to reproduce the cost
of labor-power (V1) and to maintain the machinery (V2). Usually we consider
surplus value over and above these “value” costs although in some instances
both V and SV are terms included in discussions of “value.” In either case and
in any event in our discussions we have always reduced the matter of “social
production” to its four essential elements (labor-power, technology, value and
surplus value.) With the caveat that for cross-cultural comparative purposes we
change the content of each term in a controlled way as we progress sequentially
from one sociocultural evolutionary stage to another and from one set of equations
to the next.
Shorthand in Marxist academic circles for
the “value” aspect of this productive process, as a core concept, is the phrase
“the Law of Value.” Remember, the ideal conditions, include (i) the
world as the marketplace (ii) outside regulation is absent (i.e., free unfettered competition) and
(iii) only the essential elements are included in the equations. (Labor-power
and its 4th dimension [i. e.,
time] is one element; machinery (technology) the second; value the third; and
surplus value, the fourth).
Notice that SV (surplus value) is that
additional amount of commodity produced per given unit of time which the
capitalist appropriates and it corresponds to unpaid labor-power, which is to
say also that it corresponds to unpaid socially necessary labor-time. It is
from this surplus value column that both profit and investment capital (NGM)
must come. - And, it is this fact of commodity production in capitalist systems,
which allows the capitalist to appropriate profit “honestly.” This is to say,
without the stigma of “swindling” it via
sharp trading practices.
Sometimes we say we have both paid and unpaid socially necessary
labor-time in each commodity and that saying refers to the amount of value (V1, V2) and surplus value (SV) represented in each
commodity. So in addition to
utilitarian value and exchange value,
V1, and V2 and Surplus Value, we
also have paid and unpaid labor-power
involved in each and every commodity. In practical terms this means each
worker is working part of her shift for her employer and not for herself.
If one thinks oh well the capitalists are
putting forth their factory and its equipment and the raw materials so they
deserve something. Perhaps, but remember also, the capitalists are the most
recent of a long line of sharks who got their hands on communal property, made
it theirs by force, and now confront you with the means of production in their
private hands. You say okay but in the real world how much is he taking from me
right now? Well when you see how great that is compared to what you are getting
paid then you will acquire the beginning of proletarian consciousness.
Finally, note the production of surplus
value and its rate of production is one thing. The production of profit and its
rate of production is a separate thing. Two categories frequently mixed up
together. There are many ways in which surplus value may be expended by the
capitalist and profit is just one outcome. This is of critical importance to us
because as you are about to see it is the absolute
decline in the rate of profit, not in the rate of surplus value production,
which is the at-bottom cause of the general crisis of capitalism.
Mercantile Capitalism vs.
True Capitalism
The moment long distance trade afforded
the opportunity to make a profit at both ends of a deal, since the socially
necessary labor-time involved in production is a complete unknown to the
partners on both ends, we had mercantile capitalism. That is, the accumulation
of money capital via the process of
trade.
However, in economic analysis of
sociocultural stages we must always
begin with the nature of the productive system. Thus, for true capitalism to be said to
exist in the sense of production, we
must have machinofacture extant.
Then the potential of human labor is made real because it is magnified
exponentially via the use of
machinery and via the use of the new
category of labor-power. At the end of each day you can see we can visualize
each hour as having a part of what is produced as value and another portion as
surplus value – or at the end of the day we can say X hours have produced value
and Y hours have produced surplus value - furthermore, you see profit can be
squeezed directly from said labor-power, out of the surplus value column.
Remember our definitions: Value 1 is the wage paid to the worker for his
labor; again in strictly economic terms we are purchasing the socially
necessary labor-time to use via
machinery in the production of a commodity for exchange. Value 2 is the
cost of maintaining the machinery and the factory. In this case, capital is
accumulated via production when the
owner of the machinery and the factory who is also the purchaser of the
labor-power appropriates profit from the surplus value column directly,
rather than having to swindle it via
“sharp trading practices” from a seller at one end of some deal, and a buyer at
the other.
What do we mean by
machinofacture?
The manufacture of commodities via the input of labor-power applied to
machinery is what we call machinofacture.
It is the technological heart of true
capitalism. There were originally five essential technological
elements to machinofacture; these being:
(1) a cheap and plentiful supply of highly carburized (flowing
pig) iron; from which a somewhat decarburized wrought iron was obtained (from
which steel can also be made.) This meant blast furnaces, for both the
pig iron and the decarburized wrought iron. China
had blast furnace flowing pig and wrought iron two thousand years, or more,
before it was independently invented in Liege
c. AD 1500.
(2)
Machine tools to cut and work iron and steel and make machinery.
(3) Iron and steel machinery
to produce other commodities such as pottery and textiles.
(4)
Steam engines. These were the first sources of power to be put to machine tools and
machinery independent from those of nature (wind, water, animal, human power.)
As a matter of interest the Chinese invented the steam engine many centuries
before a French priest brought a toy steam engine back to France.
This toy inspired Denis Papin to put the principles to work. The Britisher
Thomas Newcomen heard of Papin’s experiment and proceeded to build the first
steam engine in the West which was later perfected by Mr. James Watt.
(5)
Factory installation of machinery to which human unskilled labor-power could be
put to work.
In this way we see that the pure category of
abstracted socially necessary labor-time, which is to say of
commoditized labor-power, emerges and is henceforth the key to capitalist
production. This category (labor-power) was Karl Marx’s original and
unique contribution to classical political economy. Otherwise Marx accepted
most of the categories of economic analysis of Adam Smith, Ricardo, et. al. The
“proto-“steps leading toward this entirely new category in economic analysis
are what we should look for in our studies of prehistory. You will recall that we found this category clearly emergent for the
first time, in Advanced Theocratic Chiefdoms [ATC’s] (labeling it so and
assigning it the definition of being the lowest common denominator for
determining V1.) In so doing we were linking socioeconomic prehistory to
history.
Capitalism in Origin
As for the emergence of capitalism a few comments are
in order. Actually, as I have pointed
out before, we can see germinal capitalist sectors in the political economy of
both the Old World Slave and Feudal Stages (West and East) and in the New
World also. - And, as I have also pointed out, this is
because whenever labor is pooled and averaged according to some homogenizing,
averaging, equalizing equivalent to the factory clock, we have the germinal of
capitalist production.
Whenever labor-power is purchased and put
to work, whether on the land or in the factory, we have a capitalist germinal
element emergent. These germinal elements in the Old World go back to the first
city states in Sumeria, along the Nile, and in nuclear China.
The later archaeological record in Mesoamerica is replete with examples of
purchased labor put to work on the land and in factories from Olmec times
forward; in Peru,
from Chavin times forward.
In fact, you will recall that we found
proto-commoditized labor-power in the Hunting-gathering Tribes and in
Agricultural Tribes. In Stone Age Economics, as in modern Economics, one can
trace specifically defined attributes back into their previous forms and this
search for the origins of commoditized labor-power is an example.
Whydidn’t the
capitalist sector of these Ancient Slave and Feudal Stages becomeascendant
earlier? Precisely,
because machinofacture had not yet been
invented. The essential five diagnostic attributes we discussed
above simply had not yet come together in one place at one time prior to the
second half of the 1700's AD. When
they did come together in Europe and New England and in China
(and in preliminary form in other parts of the world such as Latin
America) Capitalism quickly replaced feudal land
holding as the primary source of wealth for the domesticating and ruling
classes. Quickly, is of course, a relative term. From the time of Oliver
Cromwell, a capitalist farmer himself (who purchased some labor-power each year
to use on his lands rather than taking feudal tithes from serfs), in say 1640,
until the emergence of the five essential technological elements of original
capitalism in Old and New England around 1765, 125 years passed.
Note the transition from feudalism in Europe to
Capitalism in Europe and the America’s,
was not a peaceful transition. Actually it was never a peaceful transition
anywhere. Everywhere the bourgeoisie had to fight for political power. Recent
novels and films about the transition to imperial feudalism in Japan (Shogun)
where the new class of burghers
played a role, and their later transition to full power in a stage of
Capitalism they create in their own image in Japan (The Last Samurai)
are examples on point. We should be, given the excellent historical record,
well aware of the details of this struggle whether in the English Civil War,
the American Revolutionary War, the Napoleonic Wars in Europe, the Taiping
Rebellion in China,
or the Meiji Revolution in Japan.
On the other hand academia has often spent more time in obfuscating the process
rather than in explaining what was going on - at least as far as textbooks for
the lower grades in North America
are concerned. So, in reality despite the excellent historical record there is
very widespread ignorance of the transition in countries like the USA.
However, at the time, the underlying
cause of the anti-feudal revolt among the English was not much of a secret.
This is not to say that the religious arguments of the English Revolutionaries
of 1640 to 1660 might not tend to confuse the realities of those moments today.
It is to say that a correct understanding of all of the religious arguments
among the Protestant New Model Army men and the various Parliaments of the
English Revolution period requires class analysis.
The highest class of the English
Revolution in terms of mass numbers was that of the capitalist farmers (e. g., Oliver Cromwell) - and these
capitalist farmers did have some aristocratic allies supporting them, rather
than the King and his feudal parasitocracy, precisely because they were convinced of the advantages of hiring labor rather
than having to hire men to control serfs. The next highest groups of
Republicans were the independent petty bourgeois shop holders and guildsmen
(artisans, mechanics and proto-proletarians belonging to guilds.) Finally,
there were the lowest level of the Parliamentary forces - the serfs and the
landless agricultural laborers. Each of these three groups had a name
(Congregationalist-Independents, Levelers, and Diggers) and each had a program
that became increasingly radical from top to bottom. In fact, at the bottom, we
have what Karl Marx would later call a primitive kind of communism being
preached. All three classes of the revolutionary forces tried to justify their
actions according to a particular interpretation of the Bible which began with
the Pre-Ordained Divine Plan beliefs of Oliver Cromwell and ended with the most
radical interpretations of the teachings of Jesus Christ at the bottom.
Eventually capitalism had to win out over
feudalism because the productive capacity of machinofacture was of a
qualitative order of magnitude greater than any feudal land-holding system,
even one in its finest hour. Armed with plenty of cash the bourgeoisie
eventually had to succeed.
But, they could not succeed permanently in the
years of the English Revolution and the EnglishRepublic
(wherein both the Monarchy and the House of Lords were abolished) either in Old
England or New England.
Why not? Because, the five original essential elements of
machinofacture were still over a century away when Oliver Cromwell died in
1658.
Origin of Capitalism in Europe
Karl Marx and Frederick
Engels saw the emergence of capitalism in Europe as having occurred first in
the city-states of Italy,
especially, northern Italy.
Here the city-state communes of cities like Padua had in the 1300's become concentrations of pooled, averaged,
factory clock regulated, thus commoditized, purchased labor-power alongside, or
part of, the older guild system.
Marx and Engels also recognized the
expansion of European capitalism as being intimately involved with the
discovery of gold and silver in the New
World. It was
this overnight concentration of cash wealth in the hands of the ruling classes
of Europe which gave them not just what they needed to trade with in the great
ports of the Old World, but also the capital they had to have to invest in
expensive new technology (such as the Liege blast furnace invented and invested
in heavily there beginning in 1500 - only two years after the greatest gold
strike in the history of Europe had been made in Hispaniola.)
East African, Arabian and South Asian
ports had just become open to Europeans, and for the first time, since the
collapse of the Roman Empire West c.
AD 400. Columbus
was well on his way to opening a new route to China
and the Japans even though he made it initially only as far as the Bahamas
in1492. Portuguese sailors rounded the Cape of Good Hope (South
Africa) a few
years later.
The Crusades
Remember that prior to the last decade of
the 1400's Europe
was an isolated appendage of the Eurasian land mass and all trade had to go
through expensive middle persons. The Islamic regimes of Arabia controlled most
of Europe’s trade with Arabia, East Africa, India,
Indonesia
(the Spice Islands), China
and the Japans. European ruling classes were so unhappy about this that for
several centuries they had tried everything to find a way to cut out the middle
people. Thus, for
example, the Crusades.
Yet, to no avail.
It would be the Iberians, on the tip of
the European peninsula, pursuing their natural inclinations to explore the
neighboring territories, which meant by boat, who would take the successful
route down the west coast of Africa, finding thereby the direct route to the
Far East, round the Cape of Good Hope.
Europeans on a “Cash Only”
Basis
All of a sudden, in the decade from 1492
to 1502, the European turn toward naval circumvention of the Muslims paid
off. Portuguese sailors found the tip of
Africa in the South and quickly turned northward once again from the Cape of
Good Hope making their way to Calicutt, India by way of East Africa and South
Arabia - And, Spanish privateers used the Bahamas and Cuba as their gate way
into a truly New World. Shortly they would cross Mexico
and build the direct route to East
Asia dreamed of by the Great Admiral, Cristobal Colon.
Now, the manufactured goods of the
Italian city-states, Benelux,
France,
Germany,
London, and so forth, could find their way to
the great markets of the Old World without the
intolerable cost of the Muslim interface. They could also be sold to a “made”
market of European colonials in the New World.
The enslavement of the Native Americans
provided the key thing European traders needed however, and that was cash. Gold
and silver would pay their way into Asian markets any time. Which
was essential. Because European goods were cheap and
shoddy. Furthermore, the Europeans had nothing to sell that the Asians
didn’t have in better quality and larger quantities with the exception of
English wool, White slaves, and personal firearms. The Portuguese sailors had
almost been hung in Calicutt (not Calcutta which
was a British creation later on the other side of India.
Calicutt is now Bombay
or Mumbai) when they showed up with junk like glass trading beads! (The Chinese
had had cannon for at least three centuries by this time, but had never taken
it to the level of muskets and pistols for the individual fighting man.)
Yet this period,
beginning in the late 1400's, was nothing more than what Marx and Engels said
it was, “the rosy dawn of Capitalism.” It was not true capitalism in the sense
of production via machinofacture (and
its five essential technical elements) with its cheap, unskilled, workers at
the factory bench, where their purchased labor-power was pooled and averaged
and regulated by the factory clock. In the decade 1492-1502 this was just more
mercantile capitalism. - And, so it would remain until the Europeans invented
machinery and then also brought said machinery to the masses of sub-humanized
people of South Asia, especially India.
Chief among these would be the English capitalists.
Why?
Because the French capitalists lost what
Winston Churchill has called “The First World War” (what in the USA
is often termed “The French and Indian War”) and was fought out on a
global basis. The most important part of that British global victory was not in
North America but in India
where the French were forced out for good. This “First World War” (1758-63) was
still a good two and a half centuries away from the days of rounding Good Hope
and discovering the Bahamas.
Thus, the “rosy dawn” of capitalism occurred within the Feudal Stage (albeit
it, of course, in the final Phase of said Stage.)
British Capitalism
Creates Colonial Financial Crisis
Tea Party
in Boston
It’s important for you
to recognize at this point one critical factor in the emerging post-War
(1758-1763) situation in Britain.
Yes, the Brit capitalists won the war against France,
but they did so at the cost of about 60 million pounds! Parliament took
various taxing measures including requiring the North American colonies to pay
part of the bill - at least the ongoing part of supporting British troops and
other British Government functions in the Atlantic colonies.
This was an abrogation
of the long ago won, full civic rights in colonial Assemblies, due to rich
White Yankees, in the North American system of rule by White Male Wealthy men.
The Stamp Act and other taxing pieces of legislation culminated in the Boston Tea Party and led directly to the
North American Revolutionary War (1775-1781.) The ultimate cause having
been the greed of the British capitalist’s in command of the UK Government
which led them to war in order to seize French and other possessions on a
global basis. One side effect in the end would be this greed having led
directly to the loss of the North American colonies altogether.
Technically this is a colonial war rather than an imperialist
war in that the British and French capitalists were not trying to export capital
anywhere except India
(textile factories). That is, factories and the machinery within them were not
being sent here and there and sold to anyone anywhere. Just the opposite
actually as you will see in Chapter 21 on British Imperialism versus North American colonists.
General Contradiction vs. General Crisis
As we have seen the greatest transition,
in human history, occurred many millennia before the
emergence of Capitalism. That was when the General Contradiction of the
primitive communism of the Hunting-gathering Stages and Tribal Agriculture,
expressed in the prime directive to avoid surplus production at virtually any
cost, had been replaced by the General Contradiction of the Servitude Epoch
and its prime directive; namely, to maximize surplus production regardless of
the amounts of value and surplus value being produced. This General
Contradiction of the Servitude Epoch continues in the third and final
(Capitalist) Stage of the Servitude Epoch, and, of course, in the preceding
transitional phase out of Feudalism. So, Capitalism emerges long after the
Great Divide in Human History. But, it continues with that General
Contradiction (of the Servitude Epoch) as its own. What about the General
Crisis of Capitalism?
The
General Crisis of Capitalism
As we have seen each Stage has its own
specific General Crisis. Capitalism will have its own General Crisis and we can
see it in the germinal forms from which it emerges.
In the Capitalist Stage the General
Crisis is a function of the competition between the sub-column of
“profit” and the sub-column of “investment in the Next Generationof
Machinery (NGM)” under the category we call Surplus Value.
{In this discussion of the mode of
production of the Capitalist Stage you should remember that one given
(condition of the problem) is that ‘what is produced is sold, or otherwise
realized, in the marketplace.’}
The Law of the Absolute Decline in the Rate of Profit
The General Contradiction of the
Capitalist Stage is the same as it was in the preceding Stages of the Servitude
Epoch - the drive of the domesticating, exploiting, ruling and owning classes
to maximize their profits, regardless of the amounts of value and surplus value
being produced. The General Crisis of Capitalism is, however, as Karl
Marx discovered, distinct from that of slavery. In fact, it is unique. The
General Crisis of Slavery was created when the financial cost of the police and
the army needed to keep the slaves in obedience and submission continued to
increase (not to mention the more intangible “social cost” of the Generals
realizing they could replace their employers.) In capitalism the general crisis is caused by the necessity (to stay
competitive) to continue to invest more and more money into new and continually
successive generations of machinery. In order to stay competitive each
capitalist must constantly buy new machinery that produces more commodities per
unit of labor-power employed. Even so, and therefore, unless the amount of
labor-power going into the productive process is increased on a one to one
basis with the introduction of each new unit of machinery the rate
of profit per unit of labor-power must decrease. It must decrease because the
new machinery costs a lot of money, and without increasing labor-power input,
the rate by which surplus value is increased must be relatively less than it
had been previously, precisely because of this new cost of new equipment. It is
this fact which creates the crisis. That is why we say that, at-bottom; the General Crisis of Capitalism is
caused specifically by the law of the absolute decline in the rate of
profit.
What precisely does this mean?
When the capitalist buys new equipment to
stay competitive, and to reduce the cost of the labor-power going into his
productive line, he takes a reduction in the rate of surplus value
creation. Why? Because, he reduces his work force, or reduces the hours of
labor-power of his original work force, thus reducing the hours applied to the
new machinery; simultaneously he increases the cost of “t” because of the cost
of installation and higher maintenance costs. On top of that, remember that both
the cost of the next generation of machinery (NGM) and profit
must come from the surplus value column. There is nowhere else for either to
come from. If the new machinery is ten times more productive per unit of labor
power applied to it, (more productive than the previous machinery,) the
capitalist will make more money, even after factoring-in installation and
increased maintenance costs, but there is less overall production for the
surplus value column AND HIS RATE OF PROFIT MUST FALL since we must now
factor-in the cost of the new equipment.
Again.
His rate of profit must fall for two
reasons: (1) the only way to maintain the same
rate of surplus value production (given the cost of purchasing, installing and
maintaining the new equipment) is to introduce labor-power at a one-to-one
ratio with the productive power of the new machinery. Under capitalist
relations of production this cannot be done. The idea was to reduce the cost of
labor and to stay competitive. His idea was not to hire more workers and/or to
put all these laborers to work for longer periods of time. Either one or both of
these would result in increasing the cost of Value 1 (wages), thereby
decreasing the amount of production dedicated to the SV column. (2)
Furthermore, by increasing the amount of surplus value devoted to investment in
the next generation of machinery (NGM) he further decreases the amount of
surplus value available for the profit sub-column; production which at any rate
has already witnessed an increased value 2 – i.e., increased the
magnitude of V2 (maintaining newly purchased and installed equipment). Finally
and most importantly, the capitalist must pay for the new equipment, and this
new cost factored in, reduced absolutely the amount of surplus value available
for profit.
Look at the formula:
lp + t à V1, V2 + SV
Profit/NGM
(a) (b)
(c) (d)
lp = labor-power (a)
t =
machinofacture technology (automated, cyberneticized in modern times) (b)
V1 =
wages (c)
V2 =
cost of maintaining machinery (c)
SV =
surplus value (d)
NGM =
Next Generation of Machinery the locus
of the general crisis. (d)
Profit
= that portion of surplus value appropriated by the capitalist (d)
To maintain the
rate of profit one must first maintain the rate of surplus value production by
introducing new labor-power equivalents [a] to the new machinery [b] at a
one-to-one ratio. Otherwise the percentage rate of surplus value on the right
side of the arrow must decline, as the new equipment has to be paid for also,
as does its installation and maintenance. Less surplus value means less
available for profit, because second, the complex of new machinery costs
must also come from overall value-surplus value production further reducing the
amount of surplus value available for the profit sub-column. This is an iron
law. There is no way around it.
Except in the future with robotic artificially
intelligent STAR TREK labor-power when it would be possible to introduce {a] at
the equivalent one-to-one ratio with [b] – and, where the cost of the new machinery
[d] is easily absorbed by the vastly increased productive capability of the
robotically manned overall system of production, assuming there are no social
restrictions as there are under capitalism to such a policy.
In a capitalist system this introduction of labor-power at a one-to-one ratio isn’t done, as we have seen above, so the (i) rate of surplus value production has to decline on the right side of the equation, because (ii) the heavy investment in purchasing, installing and maintaining the new machinery combine to leave less surplus value available for the profit sub-column (with V2 increasing alongside t - i. e. with “c” increasing along with “b”.) That is, the totality of costs (i.e., where these costs of “t” are accounted for under V2 and NGM) of all of this new equipment further reduces the amount of production available under surplus value for the profit sub-column. Thus the rate of profit must decline. Simple arithmetic. (Or perhaps not so simple – but, nevertheless just as real.)
There are things a capitalist can do which will ameliorate the speed by which his rate of profit will decline. Always these have to do with decreasing the cost of (a) by decreasing the amount of (c). Slave labor in Nazi systems, or simple wage control, declining safety procedures (failure to adequately maintain equipment and working safeguards) under fascist systems, are examples, but there are many other less draconian ways such as those pioneered by the North American capitalists (including “Taylorism” [i.e., efficiency] or assured US governmental contracting or simple monopoly). But in the end they are all stop-gap band-aids if you will and can only work for limited periods of time. Another topic for another book.
{Note: in Stalinist Socialist systems it has been possible to introduce labor-power at a one-to-one ratio with new machinery and new factories (via reduced wages, forced labor, volunteerism, Stakhanovism [enthusiastic worker dedication and sacrifice in production]). – And, what would have been profit is shifted instead to other sub-categories, especially NGM. Furthermore, these things were done - especially in the USSR under Stalin and in China under Mao. This is the at-bottom economic reason why both countries witnessed the early “miracle of overnight development” that was the centerpiece of attention in the world academic community of economists in the 1930s and 1950s respectively. However, there are reasons why this kind of an increase in applied labor-power cannot last forever (can only be temporary), and without giant leaps in technology which take time', but that is also another story for another book.''}
At any rate, in practice, and most
commonly, some capitalists try to maintain their rate of profit by decreasing
their investments in NGM. Eventually they lose competitive advantage. One
capitalist eats the other. Capital is concentrated and centralized. This was
discovered by Karl Marx in the mid-1840’s. Marx began
his full explication in Capital Volume
One (1867). In practice in the 20th century we have seen the
capitalist classes resorting to various extreme measures such as Nazism, a
variety of fascist practices insuring low and controlled wages, ignoring
deteriorating working conditions, and the US
system of assured governmental contracting, and always the tendency to monopoly
maximized.
Negating the Law
of Value
Free
Enterprise vs. Monopoly and Non-Competitive Contracting
Corruption
is Inherent in Capitalism
There is a widespread myth in
capitalist economics, or at least in the way it is presented to the
unknowledgeable beginning student, that “free enterprise” is an essential
characteristic of the capitalist system. Exactly the opposite is the case, in
fact. But, in Marxist theory, freedom to compete without
interference at home and/or abroad is an essentialgiven for
capitalism to function properly. What is the answer to this conundrum?
The law of the absolute decline in
the rate of profit is the at-bottom reason why the primary drive of capitalist
enterprise is always toward (1) monopoly
and further toward (2) assured
(which is to say Government guaranteed) contracts.
It has always been the case that capitalists struggled to get contracts without
competition (See Marx’s Capital Volume
III) and to assure that what competition exists exists at an absolute
minimum.
Why?
It should be obvious. If one can
obtain an assured purchase price of commodities through a monopoly on their
production or at least at a price one dictates via negotiation with a “friendly” purchaser it is a world far
preferable to one in which the law of value is allowed to dictate price. In
this way the capitalists who succeed in achieving a monopoly on producing said
commodities or at least arranging friendly (non-competitive) purchases can also
assert some control over the otherwise absolutely declining rate of profit
precisely because eliminating real competition is in effect a means of negating
the law of value. It is a form of corruption, of course. But it is so essential
to reversing the otherwise destructive tendency (to maximizing profit) created
by competition, where each capitalist must otherwise attempt to turn the law of
value to his own interest by doing something to cut costs per commodity
produced, that there is no other realistic way to turn. Corruption is as you can see, therefore, inherent in the capitalist system.
If I can get the US
government to pay me according to some assured formula (such as cost-plus “defense” [war] contracting –
that is to say, the present system
where the US
government assures me (the capitalist presenting the commodity) that I will be
paid my cost of production plus a guaranteed profit (of say 17%) I need no
longer worry about the Law of Value. At least for the moment.
No one else will be allowed to compete with me for the commodity being produced
(say a warplane) and the more I spend the more profit I will make (17% of one
billion is a lot more than 17% of half a billion). In the most egregious
contemporary cases such as the war contracting for US
imperialism in Iraq,
the process is taken to the extreme. Now, in the USA,
favored corporations are handed guaranteed cost-plus contracts without ever
having to even submit proposals for initial review (as for example competing
capitalists have had to do in the past when submitting proposals for weapons
systems, where two or three were allowed to compete). Now it is up to the
contractor to decide if a hammer is worth $1.95 or $101.95, which aside from
ethical considerations makes “price” an altogether “arbitrary” matter. (There
may be delayed checks by regulators but the key word is “delay”, because the
capitalist already has the money and has been using his ill-gotten gains for
even further profit making in some or another way.)
The desire to have
assured government contracts lies at the bottom of Western European capitalist
war contracting since the days of old. Whether in Britain
or France,
for example in the 1600’s and 1700’s, manufacturers always sought to eliminate
the law of value via corrupt
practices (buying government and legislative agents under the table) to assure
the awarding of such contracts. The same was the case in the USA
during the Revolutionary War and everywhere else the bourgeoisie fought for
power. (Cheating on quality and quantity of course is a better business
practice of all concerned but altogether aside from this inherent corruption –
a different type of corruption.)
In summary, eliminating
competition (the absolute tendency of capitalism toward monopoly) is an inherent
function of the recognition of capitalists that they could temporarily negate
the law of value and for awhile offset the absolute decline in the rate of
profit. It has its most modern manifestations in fascist systems such as those
of Germany
and Italy,
or for that matter in the USA
with its post-World War II cost-plus “defense” contracting and current
non-competitive bidding.
Now, for a few
additional comments on the birth of Capitalism.
Capitalism in the English-speaking World
As we have seen true capitalism, in the sense of
capitalist production, required a ruling class with machinofacture (and all
five of its essential minimal elements) as its profit center. Once that existed then it was possible for the middle
classes (which is what the French word “bourgeoisie” means) to mount
a serious effort to take political power away from the feudal aristocrats and
nobility. Not that these middle classes hadn’t already tried.
Britain
The first Western
Area attempt to put political power in the hands of the bourgeoisie occurred in
the English Revolution {I like to use the dates 1640 -1660 for convenience. In
actuality it would be more like 1642 - 1658.} Note that at this time the
English-speaking World consisted only of what we call the United
Kingdom and Ireland,
and the North American Atlantic Coastal Colonies with a few Caribbean
colonies thrown in. The entire English-speaking World of that time was affected
by the English Parliamentary revolt.
This revolution was eventually headed by
Oliver Cromwell who used his New Model Army as the social engineering
instrument which shaped the entire experience. The New Model Army could not be
defeated. Because of that military fact Cromwell was able to abolish the
Monarchy and the House of Lords. He created the EnglishRepublic and tried to put
political power in the hands of the bourgeoisie. But, without machinofacture as
their overwhelming profit center, the bourgeois elements, especially the
capitalist farmers, were unable to make their revolution permanent.
Cromwell’s New Model Army was based on
capitalist farmers such as himself. Why
do we call them capitalist farmers if capitalism did not yet exist as a
sociocultural stage? Because these are farmers who “hire” labor as they need
it. These are farmers who prefer not to incur the expense of hiring thugs to
control serfs. Once Cromwell died, and his military genius removed from the
class struggle, it was only a matter of time until the wealth of the
aristocrats and nobility from their traditional sources (farmers held as serfs;
and to the degree they were invested in proto-manufacturing endeavors and world
trade, from those too) reversed the political gains of the English Revolution.
For a time the traditional Monarchy and House of Lords returned. Cromwell’s
rotting corpse was exhumed and flogged and it seemed as if everything gained in
Old England by the civil wars and revolution had been lost.
Although, in Britain,
machinofacture was on the horizon, ascendant, it was not yet transcendent. It
would take another century for the five essential elements to come into play
simultaneously, thus, it took the British bourgeoisie another century to fully
take command. Although, after the post-Cromwell
“Anti-restoration Revolution of 1688,”
the British burghers were never less than equal partners with the landed
aristocracy.
North
America
At the same time, almost as if out of
sight out of mind, the New Englanders had been left alone for a good two
decades - really closer to three decades. - And, during that period of time they
had developed their own domestic political institutions.
Furthermore, the drastic labor shortage
in New England
had created a tremendous demand for every kind of gadget and invention that
could save labor-power input and magnify what labor-power input that was
available!
These are the two main reasons why
the first really successful transition to Capitalism as a sociocultural
evolutionary Stage occurred in New
England. Left to their own devices the North American
middle classes made a successful way in both the area of political life and in
the equally important area of rapidly coming to terms with the new
technological innovations. Innovations leading to germinal machinofacture! By
the time we see the Anti-Restoration Revolution of 1688 in
England,
the North Americans had plenty of experience, (nearly four decades of
practice,) in de facto self-government minus feudal interference. That
fact forever marked the further evolution of those English colonies along the AtlanticCoast.
The fighting for a new and bourgeois
dominated way of life began in North
America in 1775. Almost a century after the
Anti-Restoration Revolution of 1688 in
London.
But, its destiny was laid during the Cromwellian Revolution of 1640-1660 and
its consequences would be truly revolutionary. Semi-Capitalist farmers like
Washington and Jefferson combined with Capitalist manufacturers and
mercantilists in New England to put paid to
the extended arms of British Colonialism and the feudal order/cum
capitalist order, it represented. Since, in the British North American
colonies, the machinofacture elements were in place alongside those of
mercantile capitalism, and capitalist farming was the basis of this largely
agricultural land, and because there was only a weak native feudal (Loyalist) overstructure
to combat, the North Americans were able to pull off a successful military
struggle with some critically important help from their enemy’s principal enemy
- the French capitalists and aristocrats. That war, conducted
by George Washington and his Staff, changed history forever.
Think about it. It’s as if Cuba’s
quiet success in building Socialism may someday (say one hundred years from
now) be seen as the real beginning of true Communism, even with the collapse of
the World Socialist Stage’s homeland. Certainly, if not Cuba,
then China
may emerge as the first of the true Socialist and later Communist countries.
Not that anyone would have thought this way when everyone’s eyes were focused
on the USSR!
This is one of the advantages of having an Olympian view of prehistory and
history. It makes the comparative method of historical analysis fruitful.
However, the Cuban, Chinese or Vietnamese
situation may turn out to be as prognosticators of the future of Socialism,
there is no doubt but that the USA, tiny and virtually impotent, was the first
homeland of the first permanent truly diagnostically Capitalist Stage (minus
the Feudal residue of Great Britain) country in the World.
Why? Because all of the trappings of
power that spread awe and aura among most observers are really irrelevant to
the outcome. What are important are the underlying economic and political
diagnostics of class power. The Americans had the unhindered, critically
important social and cultural and technological elements for building capitalism,
even if the World didn’t know it until much later.
Before Industrial Slavery in
the USA
Even the
existence of slavery did not seriously, adversely, effect the North American
bourgeois success, since the slavocrat economy of the South (as we were about
to know it) was still in a rudimentary phase; the slave owners were as likely
to be neutral or supportive of the Revolution as they were to be loyalist.
Witness the slave owners Washington and Jefferson. Some of these slave owners
were more attuned to the use of free hired agricultural labor to which slavery
was a somewhat antiquated adjunct (thus, the term “semi-Capitalist.) A true
united front could therefore be, and was, forged. Industrial slavery of the
sort that followed the introduction of the Cotton Gin and the huge increase in
demand created by the textile capitalists of Europe was yet to come at the time
of the US
Revolutionary War (1775-1781).
Note that many of the textile
capitalists, especially in Great
Britain, were unusually intelligent. For
example, Frederick Engels was a
British textile magnate. Some of them were capable of foreseeing the doom of US
cotton slavery and the General Crisis of Capitalism (with it, the concomitant
need to move factories to India.)
The French Revolution Brings Capitalism to the Fore in
Europe
The Great Revolution in France,
in 1789, brought the bourgeoisie to
political power there. Let us examine a few of the reasons why capitalist
revolution in France
was so much more important to the political immediacy of the European continent
than anything the North American Revolutionary War portended.
(Bourgeoisie
is the French word for middle class; i.e.,
“middle” between the aristocracy/nobility on the one hand and the mass of dispossessed
agricultural workers and urban proletarians on the other hand.)
France
had been the heartland of Europe
since the collapse of the Roman Empire West. It was France
that had the overwhelming concentration of Western Europe’s population, which
was four times as large as the rest of Western
Europe combined. - And, the French had inherited the
infrastructure of advanced technology of the preceding Roman Slave Stage
The French Monarchy and its Consigliore would never
have consented to help the North Americans (in the US Revolutionary War of
1775-1781) with their radical political program being propagandized here and
there and everywhere, if they had really thought the Americans had any chance
of spreading such pernicious doctrines in France. The French rulers had
millennia of experience in class dictatorship and a very efficient and
effective state apparatus. At the center, were the secret police and this
police force had concentrated the French noble families (the French boss
hierarchy equivalent to Egyptian “Nome
bosses” or Chinese “scholar-bureaucrats”) at Versailles
(now a Parisian suburb). These bosses numbered some 400,000, individuals; all
deeply in debt, and under constant surveillance. The French rulers felt
confident in their ability to keep the status quo extant.
What
the French Monarchists did not understand was that Capitalism in both
manufacturing and agriculture had a new and permanent technological base. The
French “High Command” did not understand that the amount of capital being
created permanently in the hands of the owners of the capitalist farms and the
factories was overwhelming vis a vis the
traditional sources of feudal capital accumulation. - And, all of this
capitalist income was above and beyond, and in addition to, the vast amounts of
money capital being acquired globally, in everything from sharp trading to the
exploitation of slave labor in the Caribbean.
Furthermore, these new rich elements (bourgeoisie)
were not concentrated at Versailles
by the secret police – in fact, they were concentrated nowhere by the police.
They found their own favorite locales in the libraries, salons, and clubs of France’s
great cities.
At any rate, these French “middle persons” (bourgeoisie), and the intellectuals who
adhered to them could not be set aside and ignored. Yet this was something that
the Old Regime could not understand and therefore, could not
admit.
Thus, came the uprising of 1789. This
time it was the turn of the French ruling classes to experience the civil war
that their English brethren had gone through well over a century earlier.
In the event, France’s civil war quickly
spread throughout the country and ended in the liquidation of the aristocratic
and noble classes and indeed of the Monarchy and all of its institutions. In three short years. Along the way the Revolution gave the
peasantry the land of the Monarchy, the boss hierarchy, and their Church. In so
doing the Revolutionary leaders created a
vested interest in making the Revolution permanent among the masses of French
farmers. It would be these capitalist farmers that provided the
cannon-fodder for the Revolutionary Armies and those of Bonaparte a few years
later.
In the two decades following the uprising
of 1789, the French capitalist classes in various political forms, destroyed
feudalism, not only in France, and the heartland of the old Roman Empire (the
entire Riviera from Rome to Barcelona and adjacent territories), but in much of
the rest of Europe as well. This was accomplished militarily. At first under the various governments of the Revolution proper and
later under the leadership of Bonaparte.
The Congress of Victors
The Restoration of 1815
There is little new under the Sun. With the collapse
of the French Revolution/cum Empire the Feudal elements with the foreign
(Russian) troops they needed at their disposal, attempted to reverse all the
gains of the bourgeoisie. At the Congress of Vienna (the Congress of Victors),
in 1815, it may well have seemed to observers that they had succeeded. But, as
in England
with the death of Cromwell, the success of the Feudal Restorationists was
destined to be short lived. For, at-bottom, the nature of technology had changed forever. Thus, while the
political form of French government featured the restored Old Monarchical
order, the underlying economic and thus inevitably the political power would
have to be in the hands of the new, and permanently emergent, agricultural
and manufacturing middle classes.
Continental Capitalist Economic Downturn Leads to
Continental Revolution
The General Crisis of Capitalism (which we defined
above} began to come to a head in the 1830’s and finally provoked the European
wide Revolutions of 1848-50 wherein labor found its first independent political
role. This real world event triggered the acceptance of Karl Marx’s theoretical
discoveries by the European labor movement. - And, it encouraged the more
far-seeing and richest European capitalists to try sending more machinery to
the cheap labor of the colonies. Sharpest, at this hinge of historical fate, were
the British textile magnates. They envisioned India’s
cheap labor applied to their machines. They knew, from experience, about Indian
contributions to dyeing and weaving; they saw that the huge numbers of
absolutely destitute people on the Indian subcontinent could be placed at the
factory bench - burned up - replaced again - ad infinitum.
Capitalism Prospers in North
America
While the attention of Europe
was focused on its own deepening economic and political crises in the 1840's
what went largely misunderstood, or completely non-understood, was the great
success of the North American bourgeoisie. They had spread into the West and
South of territories only nominally theirs and often into territories belonging
to other nations. - And, in all these cases they were successful.
Furthermore, the technological progress
of the North Americans was phenomenal. Every kind of advanced industry existed
in at least one of the Northern cities. - And, compared to Europe,
North American capitalists had relative labor peace. When the urban proletariat
grew too angry with their conditions in factories the American capitalists had
the open valve of the West beckoning to these disaffected workers. Workers
could take their ambition and give capitalist farming a try in the West (“Go
West Young Man”). The heat was off of the pressure cooker the way it could
never be off in Europe. Thus, the North
American industrial capitalists avoided any duplication of the European
Revolutions of 1848-1850 that brought Karl Marx and his analysis of Capital,
and what needed to be done about it, to the fore. (Marx’s original “Critique”
of Capitalist production was written and circulated by him and Frederick Engels
in the mid-1840’s; and its implications were popularized by him during the
European revolutions of 1848-1850 (e. g.,The Communist Manifesto), and led to the book we know as Capital Volume One in 1867).
In fact the Gringo Regime was so stable
that it profited from the difficulties of the European rulers by completing its
seizure by 1848 of the rest of northern Mexico
including New Mexico,
Arizona and California.
Whatever the French and English may have thought about renewed Yankee
aggression there wasn’t much they could do about it with their state
apparatus’s struggling just to stay afloat.
In summary, by 1850, the North American
capitalists had not only avoided the proletarian uprisings preoccupying Europe,
but they had seized northern Mexico
as a result of their victory in the First Mexican War. They brought new
territories into the Union and California
entered as a “Free State.”
Yet, the gringo capitalists had a cancer
in their system just as deadly as the armies of unemployed workers were to
their European counterparts.
What was that cancer?
Slavery.
Free Labor vs. Slave Labor – Whither
the USA?
The US
northern Capitalists were forced to pay a high price, to their Slavocrat
counterpart rulers in the South, for California
and the West coming on board without slavery. That was the United
States
Federal “Fugitive Slave Act.” For the northern fat cats the Slavocrat South
was about to become a worse problem, at least temporarily, than the indigenous
revolts of proletarians in Europe.
The US
federal courts were as corrupt in 1850 as they are today in 2011 and the US
Supreme Court was controlled by the worst of the worst of the Southern
slavocrats. These evil men had only one interest; that interest lay in
maintaining a tight rein on their slaves. The new law created a force of
federal commissioners to hunt down fugitive slaves in any state and return them
to their owners. Even Africans who had been free for many years, and lived in Free
States could be seized and
“returned.” The commissioners were nothing more than scum-of-the-Earth
hoodlums, but they enjoyed a new legal status with the power to kill while in
pursuit of Black Men, Women and Children, and under the new US federal law
these thugs could compel citizens in Free States to assist in the pursuit and de
facto kidnapping of runaway slaves and free Blacks! Hefty fines and prison
sentences awaited Whites who refused to cooperate. A captured Black person
could not testify on his or her own behalf and was not entitled to a court
trial.
Civil War in the Offing
This Act enraged the North. Some
states reacted by passing legislation designed to hamper the federal thug’s
activities, but such laws were declared unconstitutional by the slavocrat U.S.
Supreme Court. When riots occurred in Northern communities and when soldiers
were deployed to restore order, the soldiers refused to fire on the protestors.
In Kansas
and Nebraska
the gauntlet was thrown down by Free Soilers, not about to put up with the
Fugitive Slave Act or the idea of slavery on their Free Soil! Civil War was in
the offing, as the 1852 publication of Harriet Beacher Stowe’s Uncle Tom’s
Cabin prepared the people of the North to see slavery in the South for
what it really was.
- And, the Achilles Heel of the Southern
Slavocrat Regime was laid bare for all to see. That was the running away to Canada
and Mexico
of thousands and thousands of slaves not about to put up with enslavement any
more. At least 150,000 slaves escaped to Canada,
and perhaps that many more made it to Mexico.
When the South’s evil leaders realized that their Fugitive Slave Act was going
to fail they prepared to leave the Union
and form their own tyrannical state! Those of you interested in the history of
the Slave Revolts that brought the slave system to its end should read US
Communist Herbert Aptheker’s
doctoral dissertation (published as American Negro Slave Revolts in
1943) and his earlier work on the Nat Turner Rebellion and go from there.
The First Imperialist War
By 1850, the profits returning to the capitalists of
the United Kingdom
from the factories they had installed in India
triggered the Crimean War of 1853 - 1856.
The Russian financial capitalists and their Czar hoped to seize India’s
cheap labor from the English with their massive land armies. The outcome was
devastating for the Russians and not so good for the Light Brigade.
(After Cromwell, the British rulers would
never allow promotion in the officer’s ranks except for reasons of class and
privilege. Thus, one of the most incompetent aristocrats ever to wear a British
uniform was in charge of the Light
Infantry Brigade at Balaklava.
He took a private yacht to the war zone and bedded down there with a bevy of
beauties and the best of food and service. His tactic in the crunch was to lead
his dragoons (mounted infantry), weak and dying of dysentery, straight into the
artillery of the waiting Russians, who naturally, wiped them out. Thus, Lord
Tennyson’s poem, The Charge of the Light Brigade: “Not for Us to Reason
Why; Only to Do and Die!”)
John Brown
As
the resistance to the Fugitive Slave Act spread throughout the North (and in
the South where increasing numbers of slaves were taking to the ankle express
as they headed south and north to Florida, Mexico and Canada) armed struggle
broke out. Kansas
and Nebraska
were the scene of the most violent confrontations
between free soilers and slavers. Leading the fight were men such as the
abolitionist preacher John Brown. (Abolitionist
was the popular term for those advocating the abolition of slavery.)
Brown was ready to start the US
Civil War right now (1859) and over the issue of slavery. He and his group prepared
an attack on the Harpers Ferry, Virginia,
US
Armory. This military action was to support the political objective of
initiating civil war by arousing the slave population to take up the now
available arms at Harpers Ferry.
In
the event the Army was able to defeat the insurrectionists and killed them. But
the fact the civil war did start immediately thereafter (1861) made John
Brown a hero in legend and in music (“John
Brown’s Body lies smoldering in the Grave” and “Battle
Hymn of the Republic”.) It would be four years after Harper’s Ferry before
Abraham Lincoln would issue the Emancipation
Proclamation. But, be there no doubt, John Brown’s insurrection
against slavery and the USA Government that enforced it was the first shot
fired in the US
Civil War.
Labor Takes a
Giant Step Forward – September 28, 1864
The (1st)
International Working Men’s Association
During the course of the US Civil War
(1861-1865), Karl Marx joined the {First}
International Working Men’s Association {1864 - 1876} immediately after its
September 28, 1864, London
creation. Marx rapidly became the key person holding the International together
and in shaping its composition and policies over the next 12 years.
Marx saw the opportunity to organize massive
strikes of British workers as part
of his support of the GreatRepublic,
and this made the International something to be reckoned with right
away, for the USA.
Especially after Washington (DC – the US State Department) responded warmly to
his letter to Abraham Lincoln, on behalf of the International, in which Marx
gave Lincoln
full support for the Union
in the US Civil War.
Civil
War (1861-1865) in the USA
Changes Marx’s Presentation of Capital
The US Civil War triggered the destruction of the slavocrat
overburden that the North American burgeoning bourgeoisie had inherited as a
product of the way they fought and won the Revolutionary War with Great
Britain (1775
- 1781.)
Those who have read Capital
(Volume I) know that it begins with a citation about the historic significance
of the US Civil War; but you may not know that it was that war which brought
Marx to a new way of presenting his first magnum opus to the world.
Why?
Because, from a ruling class point of
view, the struggle in the US between the Capitalist North and Slavocrat South
was fundamentally a struggle between those who advocated that labor-power be
purchased and paid at free value (therefore at a higher rate than the slave but
without the financial burden of policing the slaves) and those who advocated
that labor-power be paid at the value of minimal subsistence (the cost of
keeping the slave alive and paying those holding him in subservience).
For free workers the struggle was a
reflection of the struggle for paid hours of labor versus unpaid hours of
labor. With free workers having to compete with the lowest common denominator
(cost of keeping the slave alive) the hours for which they would be paid would
be very few indeed – thus, the status of poor Whites in the South became known
to advancing Union armies as the living conditions of “poor-White Trash.”
– And, the workers of England
and the rest of Europe
understood this very well. Although the two British working class newspapers
had started out in support of the South alongside the capitalist press (because
the “cotton famine” had shut down a great deal of the British textile
industry), Marx had been able to educate and guide them so that by 1864, as
Marx wrote to Abraham Lincoln, on behalf of the (1st) International
Workingmen’s Association, to paraphrase, “European labor has seen the struggle
of the Great Republic against Slavery as its own struggle!”
The struggle for paid hours of work, and
adequate pay at that, is the very heart of the international working class
movement – the very heart of Marxism. American workers saw that wage slavery
was bad enough and suspected what European workers already knew. Namely, any
and all capitalists would reduce them to chattel slavery if they could, because
they already done that everywhere in Europe they could, as our entire European
history and ongoing cultural connection with Europe
proved.
Three
Organizational/Structural Steps to Emancipation
1 2
3
The
International Workingmen’s The Paris
Commune The Russian Counsel
Association
(1864-1876) Model (1871) Model (1905)
From
left to right we have the initial three historical stages of organizational
awareness in the process of proletarian emancipation.
The First
International
September,
1864
Twelve
years after reaction crushed the revolutions of 1848-52 a defensive
organization led by relatively conservative British trade unionists was created
in London.
Its purpose?
To
(1) stop by physical force (on the Continent) the importation of scab labor
into Britain and (2) raise and share “strike” funds to offset the capitalist
international organization of labor and finance. It was called the
International Workingmen’s Association (and it had some definite feminine
affiliates but in these days only the most progressive males – such as Marx
himself – saw this as an absolute necessity.)
Karl
Marx joined the First (there would be three by 1919) International within a
month and volunteered his services to the cause. Marx had just inherited his
share of his parent’s estate and was financially independent for the first time
in his life. Prior to this time Marx earned money as a writer for many
newspapers, especially in other countries, and he received a great deal of
financial support from his friend the British capitalist Frederick Engels. By
this time Marx had been out of organized politics since 1852 – for twelve years
in other words.
During
those years Marx had been doing research at the BritishMuseum
library and in three more years this research would come together in the first volume of Capital (1867). Marx quickly became the ideological and
organizational leader of the First International.
In
his hands “Marxism” (the science of historical materialism) would defeat
syndicalism, anarchism and revisionism within its own ranks and the
International itself would move from being a defensive organization into an
offensive one. This development caused the most reactionary governments in Europe
to form the first anti-communist Pact.
The Paris
Commune
For
your purposes you may organize your studies in two parts. The first is understanding the specific historical circumstances
surrounding the Franco-Prussian War of 1870-1871 that led to the Civil (class)
War in France
(1871). The second is the way the Paris
proletariat organized this first attempt of the working class to establish its
own form of government.
The
second of these topics concerns what you need to internalize right now. Namely, the structure
of this first proletarian attempt at governing. No one has summarized
the governing nature and importance of the Paris Commune better than did Marx
himself in 1871 (The Civil War in
France: The Paris Commune) in the following five principal points about the
structure and indeed nature of the new Government of Paris.
(1) Elimination of the state
(professional Army) and its replacement by an armed organization of the people.
(2) Vesting of political power in
immediately recallable delegates
(3) No more than workmen’s wages be paid
any Government employee or leader
(4) Combination of executive,
legislative and judicial powers in one “working” Government rather than a
debating society of different capitalist and bourgeois interests.
(5) The entire nation from the village
to the federal level and everything in between to be governed by similar
working bodies of immediately recallable men and women paid no more than anyone
else.
In
the end the capitalists succeeded in destroying the commune and shot over
10,000 men, women and children, by firing squad, and deported to penal colonies
(e. g., Devil’s
Island) or imprisoned 14,000 more.
As
importantly, historically, the First International got the credit (or blame)
from the aristocrats, nobility and capitalists who began to form anti-communist
policies collectively. This early “anti-Comintern Pact” (the second would be
between Germany,
Italy,
Spain
and Japan
in the 1930’s) set the stage for the final conflict between workers and
capital.
The Psychological Theory of
Marxism
Marx dropped the long introductory sections on
the “history of the theory of surplus value” from Capital Volume I
(these would eventually be published by Karl Kautsky in three parts [before he
turned renegade] and today are often referred to as
Capital Volume IV by Marxist scholars.) Instead, Marx substituted “The
Commodity.” Why? Because, in and of itself the capitalist produced commodity
embodies all of the secrets of capitalist production.
Of equal importance, is that within the
commodity lie the secrets of psychological fetishism wherein “the material
relations among people appear as social relations between things.”
- And, this is the basis for the further development of the Marxist theory of
psychological imprinting which I have explained in this Handbook. In that imprinting of the underlying template of material relations
also lays the secrets of sexual fetishism, where sexual object identification
is part of the reflection of these material relations of life. These
underlying templates are (1) the altruism
of primitive communism and (2) the sadism
of the servitude epoch. In the transitional periods, both.
Without Feudalism, Without
Slavery, the Future Was Theirs
The end of the US Civil War brought both
capital and labor to the fore in North
America, as the prime interested parties, and thus the
prime movers, respectively, in advancing and defeating the Capitalist Stage.
– And, as Marx’s leadership of the First International of Workingmen, and
his services in blocking Britain’s entry into the War on behalf of the Confederate
Regime (also, blocking British construction of Naval Men of War for the
Slavocrat Regime in Richmond by organizing a giant British national strike
action), was well known to the readers of the New York Daily Herald
(for which Marx had been the London correspondent), Marxism began to make rapid
headway in the American House of Labor. Not too mention the post-1850 arrival
of real Marxists among the refugees from the European working class revolutions
of that time (1848-1850).
The New Englanders had begun their political
life in the 1600’s essentially independent of Feudalism, as we saw earlier in
this book – now they would continue it without the anachronism of Slavery.
– And, as the struggle between capitalists for the world’s cheap labor and markets
intensified, the inherent necessity of revolutionizing the means of production
did also. Let us examine this notion of revolutionizing the means of
production.
The “Form” of Surplus Value Determines its Destination
II
Machinofacture increases the productive power of human
labor exponentially; it creates huge amounts of commodities. But, the national
market is limited to the purchasing power of workers (who are paid at Value -
that is, the cost of their wages, keeping them alive [and their families]) and
the luxury living requirements of the capitalists. That is not enough. As I
pointed out in the beginning of this section, and as Karl Marx discovered, it
is the “form” of a commodity which determines its destination, thus,
also the way in which the surplus value within said commodity can be realized,
or made material, so that the capitalist can use it for his advantage.
Something besides value (I & II) and Profit must take up the excess
surplus value.
Even though the capitalists have the
world as their market (not just the nation in which production occurs), a basic
condition in the economic theory of all of Marx’s work, this is still not a
sufficient answer. No, the answer is that for the massive surplus value being
produced, to be consumed, it has to go to more constant capital (the
physical means of production) - iron isn’t eaten, it has to go to the steel
industry - steel has to feed the machine tool, machinery and construction
industries. In other words, other capitalists are often the only and best market
for all of this excess surplus value. Revolutionizing, or innovating, new means of production, offers the needed market for
all this surplus value.
Innovation
This was true then. It is just as true
now. This is the reason for the exponential increase in the rate of new
generations of equipment (Next Generation of Machinery – NGM, in our formula)
being invented and brought on-line. For example, one no sooner has a computer
than it is “obsolete.” Contemporary computer manufacturers have a “law” which says
that microprocessors will be completely reinvented (revolutionized; improved)
every 18 months. They rely on this “law” for the survival of their industry, by
recreating the marketplace continuously.
As we have seen capitalists always strive
to eliminate competition via (a)
monopoly and (b) assured (friendly; corrupt) contracting. They also use their
governments to (c) force further
innovation. For example, the US government (by way of Congressional
legislation) was recently used by manufacturing capitalists to force TV
stations across the nation to go to High Definition (by law!) despite the fact
that such technological advance means extraordinarily high costs for the
capitalists of the communications industry (not to mention the “unnecessary”
aspect of such new legally mandated equipment.)
In short, no kind of end-user capital
absorber would work unless it was constantly being reinvented
(revolutionized.) The means of
production, in other words, have to be built all over again. This is quite
feasible if the rate of improvement and innovation of the means of production
keeps apace with the need of capital to find an outlet. This is what drives
innovation in Capitalism. This is what, as Marx discovered by 1844, is
responsible for the exponentially, logarithmically increasing rate of
innovation in the means of production in Capitalist systems.
Seeds of Its Own Destruction
As constant capital (e.g.,
machinery) increases as the end-user of surplus value, and more and more
workers (the owners of their own labor-power) are sent to the street
(unemployed) with the introduction of the new machinery, generation after
generation, workers become increasingly restive. The Iron Law of Capitalist
Relations of Productionis creating its own grave digger. For
workers as a class have no choice but to struggle to seize state power; to put
an end to capitalist relations of production in favor of relations that put
them at the top of the priority list rather than at the bottom of it. Workers
must have a system of social relations that put their needs first, rather than
putting the maximization of profit for the domesticating (exploiting) few at
the top of that list. (See The Communist Manifesto, Chapter 2, Paragraph 22). Working Class power must become their
political objective.
That is why we Bolsheviks are a
working class Party. We know scientifically that only the working classes can
create humanity’s future, because only working people “have” to create such an
egalitarian future. (Again, the Star Trek model of advanced technology and
advanced social relations may be an excellent tool for educational purposes
when organizing contemporary working people.)
At any rate, after 1850, more and more
capital was sent abroad to utilize the dirt-cheap labor-power of the colonies.
The sending of more and more machinery to the colonies was the response of the
most sophisticated capitalists within the ruling classes. But most importantly
in the half-century from 1848 to 1903, was the growth of the international
organization of labor under the banner of Marxism, because the acceptance of
Marx’s discoveries was the most sophisticated response of the most advanced
workers of the capitalist world. (1848 being the European
revolutions and the appearance of TheCommunist Manifesto and 1903 being
the formation of Bolshevism.)
More and more unemployment at home
triggered revolts. The rising of workers in France in the form of the Paris
Commune of 1871; the USA revolt of workers that resulted in the St. Louis
Council of 1877, were early related events. Related because all of the capital
being sent abroad decreased still further the employment roles (workers
receiving factory wages) in both countries. (Of course, in both cases there
were many other specific factors involved in both uprisings but for our
purposes we are concerned with the role of exported capital.)
As it had been in the 1840’s, the
Americans were less affected in the 1870’s than the Europeans, by this
extra-territorial flight of Capital. This time, because of the rapid
industrialization, and expansion of industrial infrastructure, that accompanied
the destruction of slavery in half the North American nation, after northern
victory in 1865.
Nevertheless, the US
situation was exacerbated by the desire of capital to flee to quicker-return
profit-center parts of the colonial world (such as Latin
America.) In fact, the shortage of capital in the USA
was so great (initially as a consequence of Lincoln having begged and borrowed
every bit of money he could get his hands on to pay for the cost of the
“industrial” way the Union fought and won the Civil War) that Capital in Europe
was finding New York a far more profitable place to go than to stay at home.
(As a matter of interest, “James Bond” creator, one-time MI6
agent, Ian Fleming, owed much to his
grandfather, who became one of Britain’s richest men by making 40 odd trips
back and forth from Scotland to New York with bags of cash he was able to raise
overnight in the UK for railroad and other industrial investment in the US and
the US Latin American de facto
colonies; the senior Fleming starting as a simple clerk who noted upon arrival
in New York, with the end of the Civil War, that capital invested brought two
to three times as much in the US as in his homeland of Scotland.)
Worker’s parties began to appear in the
European capitals of Capital. Parties which took Karl Marx
and Frederick Engels as their mentors (even though both men were often at odds
with these would-be offspring.)
These years were also the years of
maturation of the phase of imperialism
of the Capitalist Stage. Imperialism is the last phase of the Capitalist Stage.
However, this phase has proven to be of over one hundred fifty years in
duration, and we can now see that it will continue well into the 21st century,
despite the fact that both Stages of Socialism are now extant on the historical
stage.
Revisiting the European Working Class Movement
The Twenty Years between Marx and Lenin
During
the years of the First International (1864-1876) Marx battled the anarchists
and the syndicalists for control of that body. At the same time a group
of reforming type (soon to be called “revisionist”) socialists was
emerging in Germany.
All of these tendencies were in serious theoretical error.
Mikhail
Bakunin (1814 – 1876) (one of the two principal anarchist leaders of that time
the other being Pierre-Joseph Proudhon) exposed anarchism’s theoretical
bankruptcy during that fight by maintaining that humans were innately
incapable of behaving in any way other than one in which some would rise above
the others, regardless of any other circumstances. The few structured above
everyone else, using armed force, (the state), would always compel those below
to act as they dictated. This is a kind of primitive biological determinism
in that it takes its cue from the idea that humans are genetically programmed
to behave in this way. As such it is categorically wrong by definition.
In
other words, this is part of the fundamental theoretical error in anarchist
sociology. Marx and Engels had discovered the science of anthropology (culture)
and the growth of that science ever since (and all four of its subdisciplines)
tell us that it is not the structure of society which leads to the evils of
class dictatorship but the economy of society. That is, the three components of
culture (technology, social organization and ideology) act as if they were
straddled with “governors” (negative feedback style) so that no one component
can get too far out of sync with the other three, and all together comprise the
buffer between humans and nature. This buffer we call culture has its own laws
of causality and process. There is no genetic predetermination in humans as far
as social behavior is concerned. This is scientific law today and written in
stone but in those times it had not yet garnered the massive proof that
anthropology would provide in the 20th century.
The
Syndicalists like the anarchists came in a variety of schools and
movements but they too were defeated in the First International in that they
could not come to accept Marx’s proof that the state is the instrument of
arising classes and not the cause of class division. Thus, the Marxists
insisted that the cap state be destroyed first so that the socialist state
could be constructed and take its place. Only after the
elimination of the causes of the state (classes and class war) could one talk
about the abolition of the state altogether.
Arising
at the same time was a school of Right-wing social democratic Reformists (who
would soon be called evolutionary socialists or “revisionists”) which
advocated in one form or another participating in the bourgeois political
formation (parliaments for example) and in struggling for working class
immediate welfare needs such as the eight hour day, social security, medical
care, public schooling and so forth.
This
latter group claimed Marx and Engels as their theoretical founders but in fact
they took these great social scientists work along an entirely new road. Marx
and Engels saw participating in all forms of struggle (thus all political forms
within capitalist society) as essential to building a base for the eventual
armed insurrection and violent overthrow of the cap state. The
reformists however had an entirely different take. They came up with one
excuse or another to substitute the idea that this kind of struggle would lead
to peaceful parliamentary evolution out of capitalism into socialism. This
completely self-serving fallacious doctrine became the basis of “revisionism”
(led by the German Social Democrats such as Bernstein and Kautsky.)
As
the Syndicalists and the Anarchists went their own way after 1876 so did these
reforming revisionists. When Marx died in 1883 they had spawned nearly
identical reformist-revisionist parties in most of the rest of the countries of
Europe. In
1889 these parties came together and formed the Second International
Association of Workingmen.
In
the twenty years between Marx’s death in 1883 and Lenin’s founding of the
Bolshevik Party in 1903 the principal fight within the European Working Class
Movement ceased being between Marxism on the one hand and Syndicalism/Anarchism
on the other hand and now became a fight between orthodox Marxists and
Revisionist Marxists.
- And,
so there we stood.
Why Racists and Fascist Radio Nutballs Sometimes
Succeed
As you can see the laws of capitalist
production were not easy to discover. Frederick Engels remarked in his 1883
funeral eulogy to Karl Marx in London,
that the unlocking of the “secrets” of capitalist production was one of Marx’s
two greatest contributions. (The other being the discovery of the laws of
history as we reviewed earlier; in the USA
what is more often thought of as the tripartite nature of the (anthropological)
concept of “culture.”)
Workers know they are being exploited but
the mechanics of that exploitation are difficult for them to understand in many
cases. After all it took the genius of Karl Marx to explain the process to
intellectuals. As a consequence workers have often fallen victim to all kinds
of persons who would trick them. Fascist radio nutballs like Rush Limbaugh for
example and others like Hitler and Mussolini use populist language as the first and foremost trick after racism -
Hitler put the words “socialist” and “workers” in the name of his Nazi Party
(National Socialist German Workingmen’s Party.)
Our
task is to set the record straight and educate those workers we can reach who
have been misled. Because, if we don’t, and we allow them to become Nazi’s, we
will end up having to kill them somewhere down the road in the inevitable armed
struggle.