The archaic human populations we call Homo
erectus evolved into Homo sapiens or modern people with roughly 1500
cubic centimeters of cranial capacity by one million years ago. All of the erectus
populations made this journey. There was no fantasy-land separation of the
grades of humanity with some pockets left behind. Culture was always the factor
being selected for. Technical competence and social organizational and
ideological sophistication were the universals responsible for nature acting in
favor of the increasing cranial capacity. That’s the end of that story.
Broad-spectrum
Wild Resource Exploitation is a Revolution
Triggering
a new General Crisis
What is new and revolutionary to
understand is that these Homo sapiens populations faced the crisis of
broad-spectrum wild resource exploitation for the first time. The ability to
exploit virtually every living animal and plant resource was at hand.
Why was this a
crisis?
Because such exploitative ability has
within it the assurance that surplus social product is increasingly likely as
an outcome - exactly the opposite of what all this social time expenditure of
millions of years was about. By dumping social time in the ways we have just
discussed, primitive people managed to stave off the terminal deepening of the
crisis of increased competence in production (too much on hand) until now - now
the “potential” of nearly unlimited surplus social product on hand could no
longer be deferred. In other words, the broad-spectrum wild resource revolution
which had been inherent abstractly, was now at the
door. It was the enemy at the gate and the ways of a million years or more
would no longer suffice to ameliorate the outcome. Every step they would now
take to delay the inevitability of surplus social product on hand instead made
having it on hand the immediate and irreversible result. A
true dialectical irony.
The archaeological evidence is universally in line with
this interpretation and compellingly conclusive in this regard. We see all over
the Old World from seaside camp villages on the French Riviera {c. 400,000 BP}
to grassland burning South African bands
{c. 100,000 BP;} to the Chinese of Choukoutien {500,000 to 100,000 BP} that
people had learned a very great deal about their environments and had started
controlling them in a variety of ways. Not the least of the results of that
control was the ability to spend long periods of time in one place. - And, to produce
quite sufficient social product with a relative minimum of labor input. Social affluence now achieved with an
absolute minimum of labor input.
The classical work on this “Original Affluent Society” is
published as the first paper in the book Stone Age Economics, by
Marshall Sahlins.(the original edition, was published in 1974 by Tavistock,
London, and is available in all libraries of tertiary institutions; a new 2004
edition is available from Routledge, London, 348pp.) Those of you seriously
interested in Anthropological Economics in the cross-cultural comparative
sense, are urged to study that text.
These Hunter/Gatherers could work less
hours and do other more creative things. But, although the reduced labor-time
input into production could keep the output to just Value – creative
activity also led to more knowledge about the world - which implied
the ability to produce even more social product. An excellent
example of an emerging dialectical opposite.
The First
proto-Commoditized Labor-Power
Occurs
Among Homosapiens Advanced Hunter-Gatherer Tribes
Often these larger kin units engaged in group production, where the concrete
laboring activities of the individual were de facto abstracted, through
joint communal effort. The cliff-jumping of herds; netting of migrating fish;
the planned burning of grasslands to encourage the growing of certain nut
trees, are examples of “pooling” labor-power. Even though these pooled labor-power categories were not
governed by the modern “homogenizer” of labor power - the factory clock
- we can see that labor-power has been placed in a clearly “proto” position
with regard to this kind of homogenized labor-power production for there is a certain amount of time regulation – even if it is only
“we work from dawn to dusk” - and thus, we can say in strictly economic terms,
that the next step for this primitive (proto-) homogenization of labor-power
is the actual commoditization of
labor-power, in that this proto-labor power could be allocated to community or inter-community tasks and/or otherwise
put up for exchange. A more precise
term, given our temporal perspective, would be that this pooling of labor-power
in primitive hunting and gathering Tribes is a form of “proto-commoditized” labor-power.
With the advent of animal and plant
domestication, the tribal form of life was already very much on the horizon in
the Old World.
MacNeish’s studies show that in the New
World without the domesticated animal component, Bands
were often the basic social organizational form by which the arts of
subsistence were practiced prior to serious reliance on plant domesticates made
semi-sedentary agricultural village (Tribal) life possible. - And, this kept
Band society around several millennia longer in the Western Hemisphere, as
compared to the rate of change in the Old World centers of agricultural
revolution (with their numerous potential animal and plant domesticates); where
Bands quickly transformed into the larger Tribal unit; but the process is and
was identical.
This is the general crisis of all
hunting and gathering bands and tribes.
By 110,000 BP we see tool kits of
intricate content all over the Old
World in archaeological sites. These specialized tools
reflect deep knowledge about environments and ways to exploit and control them.
Most importantly from our perspective these specialized tools reflect the great
amount of labor-time devoted to experimentation with and perfection of said
tool kits. - And, increasing emphasis on time consuming “beauty” in the manufacture
of utilitarian items.
By 20,000
years ago people were making the final steps toward irreversible release of
surplus social product. Or, another way of putting it is that they were making
their first tentative steps into the agricultural revolution. Over the next
five to ten thousand years (say 20,000
BP to 10,000 BP), in center after center of the origin of animal and plant
domestication, people would become irreversibly committed to this new
(agricultural) way of life. Producing food rather than collecting it. - And, in
this process they would come face-to-face, finally, with the enemy within.
At the core of this transition is the
reality that social time consumed in experimentation, perfection and
beautification of tools (rather than engaging social time in direct production
[i.e., hunting and gathering]) had
back-lashed into making people even more capable of creating social surpluses
than they were before.
The General Crisis continues (produce
enough, but no more) in a more sophisticated form of extraordinarily complex
social time usage. Nevertheless this increased concentration on thinking
abstractly in order to engage in such extraordinary social time dumping is
simply exacerbating the rate of development of this tendency to potentially
being able to really significantly increase production by making it certain
people know more and more about plants and animals and every other aspect of
their objective daily lives. In other words, the more they know about nature
because of this extraordinary amount of thought and time devoted to de factolearning, the more they
could if they wished increase their production. The proof lies in the fairly
rapid emergence of broad-spectrum exploitation in the latter part of the Lower
Palaeolithic and then in the Middle and Upper Palaeolithic and its in turn transformation into the agricultural revolution!
Finally, we consider this a distinct sociocultural evolutionary change because
of the extremely acute nature of the General Crisis and the biological
evolution of the carriers to having 1/3 more cubic cranial capacity (and
presumably smarter too.)
The new formula looks like
this:
l + t à V1, V2 + Surplus
Social Product
Non-productive
time creates more
Productive
potential
l =
human concrete laboring activity
t
= Middle and Upper Palaeolithic
and Mesolithic tools
V1
= cost of life
V2
= cost of maintaining technology
Surplus
Social Product = proto-surplus value about to be irreversibly released
productive potential.
__
= This is the locus of the general crisis
of hunting and gathering, as it has been, but it is now acute.